Bask - Shop now
Buy new:
$31.49
FREE delivery Saturday, April 12 on orders shipped by Amazon over $35
Ships from: Amazon
Sold by: YnsSeller
$31.49
Get Fast, Free Shipping with Amazon Prime FREE Returns
FREE delivery Saturday, April 12 on orders shipped by Amazon over $35
Or fastest delivery Friday, April 11. Order within 5 hrs 10 mins
Only 1 left in stock - order soon.
$$31.49 () Includes selected options. Includes initial monthly payment and selected options. Details
Price
Subtotal
$$31.49
Subtotal
Initial payment breakdown
Shipping cost, delivery date, and order total (including tax) shown at checkout.
Ships from
Amazon
Amazon
Ships from
Amazon
Returns
30-day refund/replacement
30-day refund/replacement
This item can be returned in its original condition for a full refund or replacement within 30 days of receipt.
Payment
Secure transaction
Your transaction is secure
We work hard to protect your security and privacy. Our payment security system encrypts your information during transmission. We don’t share your credit card details with third-party sellers, and we don’t sell your information to others. Learn more
$9.50
Get Fast, Free Shipping with Amazon Prime FREE Returns
Book is in good condition and may include underlining highlighting and minimal wear. The book can also include From the library of labels. May not contain miscellaneous items toys dvds etc. . We offer 100% money back guarantee and 24 7 customer service. Free 2-day shipping with Amazon Prime! Book is in good condition and may include underlining highlighting and minimal wear. The book can also include From the library of labels. May not contain miscellaneous items toys dvds etc. . We offer 100% money back guarantee and 24 7 customer service. Free 2-day shipping with Amazon Prime! See less
FREE delivery Saturday, April 12 on orders shipped by Amazon over $35
Or fastest delivery Friday, April 11. Order within 5 hrs 10 mins
Only 1 left in stock - order soon.
$$31.49 () Includes selected options. Includes initial monthly payment and selected options. Details
Price
Subtotal
$$31.49
Subtotal
Initial payment breakdown
Shipping cost, delivery date, and order total (including tax) shown at checkout.
Access codes and supplements are not guaranteed with used items.
Kindle app logo image

Download the free Kindle app and start reading Kindle books instantly on your smartphone, tablet, or computer - no Kindle device required.

Read instantly on your browser with Kindle for Web.

Using your mobile phone camera - scan the code below and download the Kindle app.

QR code to download the Kindle App

Follow the author

Something went wrong. Please try your request again later.

Triumph of the City: How Our Greatest Invention Makes Us Richer, Smarter, Greener, Healthier, and Happier Hardcover – February 10, 2011

4.5 out of 5 stars 824 ratings

{"desktop_buybox_group_1":[{"displayPrice":"$31.49","priceAmount":31.49,"currencySymbol":"$","integerValue":"31","decimalSeparator":".","fractionalValue":"49","symbolPosition":"left","hasSpace":false,"showFractionalPartIfEmpty":true,"offerListingId":"P0L7ClN2iOcZ79vWmKOFoX9GjvgOQCQkyiO1bIyRzID1D25GfmzIcWN2EnM8AMYmbZLuvB3NyK%2FAvurcqWTDwwyz%2FZ72jtYrbAEHI4Gebv0ySCcE2hR9KdKiJJHmx%2BJ8Jf1c1Yrd5UGu4U6hkL6agFSvmhKRqiv5dkoHH7ntEj7BwXYcJIpLuGhss2nF4LvG","locale":"en-US","buyingOptionType":"NEW","aapiBuyingOptionIndex":0}, {"displayPrice":"$9.50","priceAmount":9.50,"currencySymbol":"$","integerValue":"9","decimalSeparator":".","fractionalValue":"50","symbolPosition":"left","hasSpace":false,"showFractionalPartIfEmpty":true,"offerListingId":"P0L7ClN2iOcZ79vWmKOFoX9GjvgOQCQkwk4CrY5vAH5RFRszptTaU4Q5weEuURecm0Xi4V9Xv91rSIbg6YHFsKqwpBWvRp9wcPUQX9KAGOVw0eiTzKy0l7fnxyZu1ho46cDlg4Pr8%2BmKgsGhwvAybbZlOx4po24%2FlrBsERSrClnH%2B0lHZ%2B05Izk6FTBg2Gy%2F","locale":"en-US","buyingOptionType":"USED","aapiBuyingOptionIndex":1}]}

Purchase options and add-ons

A pioneering urban economist offers fascinating, even inspiring proof that the city is humanity's greatest invention and our best hope for the future.

America is an urban nation. More than two thirds of us live on the 3 percent of land that contains our cities. Yet cities get a bad rap: they're dirty, poor, unhealthy, crime ridden, expensive, environmentally unfriendly... Or are they?

As Edward Glaeser proves in this myth-shattering book, cities are actually the healthiest, greenest, and richest (in cultural and economic terms) places to live. New Yorkers, for instance, live longer than other Americans; heart disease and cancer rates are lower in Gotham than in the nation as a whole. More than half of America's income is earned in twenty-two metropolitan areas. And city dwellers use, on average, 40 percent less energy than suburbanites.

Glaeser travels through history and around the globe to reveal the hidden workings of cities and how they bring out the best in humankind. Even the worst cities-Kinshasa, Kolkata, Lagos- confer surprising benefits on the people who flock to them, including better health and more jobs than the rural areas that surround them. Glaeser visits Bangalore and Silicon Valley, whose strangely similar histories prove how essential education is to urban success and how new technology actually encourages people to gather together physically. He discovers why Detroit is dying while other old industrial cities-Chicago, Boston, New York-thrive. He investigates why a new house costs 350 percent more in Los Angeles than in Houston, even though building costs are only 25 percent higher in L.A. He pinpoints the single factor that most influences urban growth-January temperatures-and explains how certain chilly cities manage to defy that link. He explains how West Coast environmentalists have harmed the environment, and how struggling cities from Youngstown to New Orleans can "shrink to greatness." And he exposes the dangerous anti-urban political bias that is harming both cities and the entire country.

Using intrepid reportage, keen analysis, and eloquent argument, Glaeser makes an impassioned case for the city's import and splendor. He reminds us forcefully why we should nurture our cities or suffer consequences that will hurt us all, no matter where we live.
Books with Buzz
Discover the latest buzz-worthy books, from mysteries and romance to humor and nonfiction. Explore more

Frequently bought together

This item: Triumph of the City: How Our Greatest Invention Makes Us Richer, Smarter, Greener, Healthier, and Happier
$31.49
Get it as soon as Saturday, Apr 12
Only 1 left in stock - order soon.
Sold by YnsSeller and ships from Amazon Fulfillment.
+
$12.39
Get it as soon as Saturday, Apr 12
In Stock
Ships from and sold by Amazon.com.
+
$10.37
Get it as soon as Saturday, Apr 12
In Stock
Ships from and sold by Amazon.com.
Total price: $00
To see our price, add these items to your cart.
Details
Added to Cart
Some of these items ship sooner than the others.
Choose items to buy together.

Editorial Reviews

From Booklist

Glaeser�s academic specialty, urban economics, informs his survey of how cities around the world thrive and wither. Using a range of expository forms�history, biography, economic research, and personal story�he defines what makes a city successful. That changes through time, and a flourishing Industrial Age model may not work in the service-age economy, as rust-belt towns like Detroit have learned. One thing constantly attracts people to one city rather than another�how much housing construction is permitted. Restrictive places, such as New York City, coastal California, and Paris, have a tight housing supply with prices only the wealthy can afford. Hence, middle-class people move to the suburbs or cities like Houston. Other features of metropolises�their incidences of poverty and crime, traffic congestion, quality of schools, and cultural amenities�also figure in Glaeser�s analysis. Whatever the city under discussion, Mumbai or Woodlands, Texas, Glaeser is discerning and independent; for example, he believes that historic preservation isn�t an unalloyed good and that bigger, denser cities militate against global warming. Thought-provoking material for urban-affairs students. --Gilbert Taylor

About the Author

Edward L. Glaeser is the Fred and Eleanor Glimp Professor of Economics at Harvard University. He studies the economics of cities, housing, segregation, obesity, crime, innovation and other subjects, and writes about many of these issues for Economix. He serves as the director of the Taubman Center for State and Local Government and the Rappaport Institute for Greater Boston. He is also a senior fellow at the Manhattan Institute. He received his Ph.D. from the University of Chicago in 1992.

Product details

  • Publisher ‏ : ‎ Penguin Press (February 10, 2011)
  • Language ‏ : ‎ English
  • Hardcover ‏ : ‎ 352 pages
  • ISBN-10 ‏ : ‎ 159420277X
  • ISBN-13 ‏ : ‎ 978-1594202773
  • Item Weight ‏ : ‎ 1.4 pounds
  • Dimensions ‏ : ‎ 6.5 x 1.13 x 9.56 inches
  • Customer Reviews:
    4.5 out of 5 stars 824 ratings

About the author

Follow authors to get new release updates, plus improved recommendations.
Edward L. Glaeser
Brief content visible, double tap to read full content.
Full content visible, double tap to read brief content.

Edward Glaeser is the Fred and Eleanor Glimp Professor of Economics at Harvard. He is widely regarded as one of the most innovative thinkers around and when not teaching has spent his professional life walking around and thinking about cities.

Customer reviews

4.5 out of 5 stars
824 global ratings

Review this product

Share your thoughts with other customers

Customers say

Customers find this book well-researched and informative, particularly praising its coverage of urban studies. The writing style is concise and easy to understand, with one customer noting how it seamlessly blends historical narrative. They appreciate how cities magnify humanity's strengths and promote growth, while leaving a smaller carbon footprint.

AI-generated from the text of customer reviews

70 customers mention "Insight"63 positive7 negative

Customers find the book insightful and well-researched, making it a good resource for urban studies.

"...of racial minorities have generally been more effective in establishing good community relations...." Read more

"...are some shortcomings, his overall point is well thought out and researched...." Read more

"...Edward Glaeser’s book is a fascinating piece of non-fiction. It’s compelling and though provoking. I cannot recommend it highly enough." Read more

"...of an economist, but the professor provides many interesting vignettes on the architecture and indeed the literary and historical background of some..." Read more

57 customers mention "Readability"53 positive4 negative

Customers find the book highly readable, describing it as a fantastic and mind-blowing pop-econ book that is persuasive and well-argued.

"...While there are some shortcomings, his overall point is well thought out and researched...." Read more

"...Edward Glaeser’s book is a fascinating piece of non-fiction. It’s compelling and though provoking. I cannot recommend it highly enough." Read more

"...Overall, this is not a bad book, but it is not a great book either. The historical bits are more interesting than the persuasive bits...." Read more

"...The book is really readable and interesting. It offers insights for policy makers as well as casual readers...." Read more

28 customers mention "Writing style"25 positive3 negative

Customers appreciate the writing style of the book, finding it concise, easy to read, and thoroughly written, with one customer noting how it seamlessly blends historical narrative.

"...It is easy to read, although I confess that in certain parts I had difficulty in reconciling some of the contrasting arguments and views put forward..." Read more

"This book offers some interesting narrative on the history of cities, but Glaeser's arguments about the importance of cities in the modern world..." Read more

"...All his qualities transpire here. Yet The book reads easily. The economics and statistics are clearly explained...." Read more

"...I find the accessible writing style enabled me to grasp key concepts without specialized expertise...." Read more

26 customers mention "City development"26 positive0 negative

Customers appreciate how cities magnify humanity's strengths and promote growth, with one customer noting that strong educational institutions are beneficial for urban areas.

"...Glaeser put it, "The central theme of this book is that cities magnify humanity's strengths...Our culture, our prosperity, and our freedom are all..." Read more

"...provides an interesting angle, and many important and counterintuitive insights about cities: that density is necessary, skyscrapers are good, slums..." Read more

"...It discusses issues that constrain and promote city growth as well as positive and negative externalities that come with living in close proximity...." Read more

"...A big reason to like cities is that big cities are best for the environment...." Read more

11 customers mention "Environmental impact"11 positive0 negative

Customers appreciate the book's positive environmental impact, noting that cities leave a smaller carbon footprint and are healthier places to live. One customer specifically mentions the economic and environmental efficiencies of urban living, while another highlights the great environmental advantages of building up.

"...City residents have higher standards of living, healthier lives, and are more environmentally conscious...." Read more

"...The author also discusses the energy efficiency of cities in maximising utility of many public goods but also the need for sanitation to prevent..." Read more

"...They leave a smaller carbon footprint, compared with the sprawling suburbs...." Read more

"...Core ideas about the value of propinquity, of access to innovation, and the economic and environmental efficiencies of urban living are stimulating..." Read more

Top reviews from the United States

  • Reviewed in the United States on September 12, 2011
    The author argues cities are economically and culturally better places to live than non-urban areas. City residents have higher standards of living, healthier lives, and are more environmentally conscious.

    Glaeser argues that January temperatures are leading indications of economic growth in cities. Our poor treatment of cities in recent decades has led to greater income inequality, greater economic difficulties, and more environmental problems nationwide.

    Two thirds of Americans, or about 253 million, live on 3% of our land that is urban.

    New York supplanted Boston as the busiest British colonial port due to shipping wheat and flour which went mostly to Southern colonies. Transportation improvements brought more people to cities. New York declined as a manufacturing area as the global markets grew, yet it remained as a place where people with ideas could comingle, in areas such as academic knowledge, financial innovations, and clothing designs. New York rebounded from financial troubles in the 1970s to where 40% of Manhattan employees are in financial services. Wages increased in Manhattan faster than in all large cities. Manhattan wages are 17% above the national average and 45% above Santa Clara County, a.k.a. Silicon Valley.

    Nationwide, city employees earn 30% more than non-metropolitan employees.

    Cities globally "are gateways between markets and cultures."

    The author argues Jane Jacobs was wrong that older and shorter buildings would be cheaper. Increasing the supply of housing by building more buildings that are taller decreases housing prices. The author agrees with Jane Jacobs that cities should be very accessible to pedestrians and they should exude creativity.

    Historic preservation has its place, according to the author. Yet, Glaeser noted that reducing construction of new homes decreases its supply and increases housing costs. Paris, for instance, is well preserved yet only the wealthy can afford to live there.

    Sprawl increases commute times, harms more of the environment, and decreases the sense of community amongst residents. Cities, by comparison, have fewer carbon emissions. Urban dwellers use more mass transit. New York City residents use less gas on average than do residents of any other city.

    Athens was a great sixth century B.C. city where much of Western philosophy originated and was explored by many in close residence. Rome had fewer cities and collapsed in part because it had trouble maintaining its many roads and vast infrastructure.

    One thousand years ago, three of the four cities with over 50,000 people had Islamic residents, namely Seville, Palermo, and Cordoba. The fourth was Constantinople.

    Baghdad in Fifth Century B.C. was a center of exchange of scholastic, philosophical, and mathematical knowledge. Merchants were enriched with a collection of buyers in close proximity.

    Nagasaki, beginning in 1543, became a major trading city with Western merchants.

    Bangalore was a center of engineering advancements. It remains an international leader in computer and information technologies.

    Entrepreneurial advances in information will be what guides future growth.
    Cities that adapt to the demands of information will grow economically, Glaeser predicts. Those that don't will not grow.

    Cities that declined in recent years tried to hold on their industrial base, which itself was declining. The cities that grew reinvented themselves and attracted new and growing enterprises.

    New York expanded through entrepreneurship. Financial sector employees eared over $78 billion in New York City in 2008.

    Some cities declines decline, in part, by what the author calls the "Curley Effect", named after former Boston Mayor James Michael Curley. Mayor Curley called Anglo Saxons "a strange and stupid race", an intended insult for many wealthier Bostonians. Some cities that declined actively drove out its wealthier residents. Successful cities attracted wealth and investors.

    The author argues the Federal government should allow all people to keep more of their own money. He opposes Federal government policies that help specific locations. He also notes more government programs divert money towards those who are political connected.

    Many cities have large numbers of poor residents. Cities that have grown offered ways for poor people to advance themselves. This created new wealth that helped increase the city's overall wealth.

    Government programs on poverty typically target poor people in cities rather than in rural areas. Government programs that help the poor often encourage more poor people to move to cities to access these programs. This further increases urban poverty. A city will improve it is can enable its poorer residents to improve their economic situations.

    Empowerment zones were a government program that successfully created jobs for low income workers. Yet it did so at a cost of about $100,000 per job created.

    Glaeser argues housing vouchers to low income people allows them to move into improved housing. It also puts public funds into the control of residents rather than the control of builders. Builders often are politically connected and are more prone to use public funds exorbitantly. Studies, though, have shown mixed results with housing vouchers. Overall, African American women improve their lives with vouchers while African American males do not fare as well with vouchers.

    Glaeser argues the best Federal policies for poverty are ones that lower artificial barriers between the wealthy and the poor. Policies that provide more to schools in wealthier schools than poorer schools, as often happens currently, only increases the gap between richer and poorer people.

    School quality disparities have prevented urban growth in cities such as Detroit. Wealthier people leave urban areas for better schools in the suburbs.

    Werner Troesken conducted an economic analysis that showed that, in the late 19th century and early 20th century, cities that invested in municipal waterworks significantly lowered deaths from water borne illnesses. Many troubled cities today, such as Dharavi and Kinshasha, would benefit from investments that reduce diseases and illnesses.

    Gilles Duranton and Matthew Turner conducted economic analysis that indicates vehicle miles traveled increases with each mile of new road. Thus, constructing new roads does nothing to lessen congestion.

    William Vickrey's economic analysis shows that vehicle drivers do not factor the lost time costs to other drivers. The economic market answer would be to charge drivers for the congestion they create, such as increasing tools during times of high congestion. London adopted congestion pricing which greatly reduced congestion. So far, the concept of congestion pricing has not been politically viable in the U.S., even though its costs are in the billions of dollars.

    An increase in population increases the number of criminal suspects. This makes it harder for police to solve crimes. A doubling of a population reduces crimes solves by approximately 8%.

    "Close-knit" communities reduce crime, even in urban areas. Residents watching their neighborhoods that deal with problems when they arise have lower crime rates.

    There seems to be no explainable reasons why crime rates fluctuate. The only correlation found is that increases in the number of young people, who commit the most crimes, account for about one fifth of increases in crime. John Donohue and Steve Levitt argue that legalizing abortion led to their being fewer troubled youth which led to lower crime rates.

    Crime rates reductions correlate with arrest rates increases more so than with increasing incarceration sentences.

    Tougher penalties for drug laws and other crimes increased the number of people in the criminal justice system (incarcerated, on parole, or on probation) from 1.8 million in 1980 to 6.4 million in 2000. Having fewer criminals on the streets lowered violent crimes by 40% during the 1990s. Much debates centers on the increased incarceration of nonviolent criminals. Many of the people who are incarcerated for nonviolent crimes would otherwise lead productive lives, yet some are also violent criminals who were caught more easily committing nonviolent crimes. Society has to weight the costs of denying freedom and reducing the prospects of nonviolent criminals versus lowering crime rates, Glaeser recommends.

    Another factor in lowering crimes rates during the 1990s was that there was a 15% increase in the number of police officers. Steven Levitt claims this lowered crime by 5%. An advantage to hiring more police is they are less costly than incarcerating people.

    Jack Maple mapped high crime areas in the New York transit system. The New York Police Chief then mapped crime areas in New York. A computer model helped them assign resources to where criminal activity was most occurring.

    Cities began reinstating police officers patrolling neighborhoods which the officers knew. Good community contacts helps officers gain trust and to receive information from local residents. Neighborhood patrols were changes from previous concepts of rotating police officers. They were rotated after corruption cases where people were bribing officers known to them.

    Neighborhood advisory councils often help police officers. It is noted that police officers who are female and/or of racial minorities have generally been more effective in establishing good community relations.

    Suicides and accidents are major reasons of death for younger people. Urban areas have lower suicide and accident rates. New York vehicle deaths are 75% lower than the rest of the nation. The New York suicide rate is 56% less than the rest of the nation. Gun ownership is four times higher in smaller towns than in urban areas.

    New York residents aged 54 to 64 have 5.5% lower fatalities than deaths nationwide, 17% less for New Yorkers aged 64 to 74, and 24% less for New Yorkers aged 75 to 84.

    Urban residents are most active. Compared to rural residents, urban residents are 98% more likely to see a movie, 44% more likely to see a museum. 26% more likely to drink at a bar, and 19% more likely to go to a rock or pop concert.

    Urban residents spend 25% more on footwear.

    The 284 foot spire of Trinity Church was once New York's tallest structure until 1890 when the New York World skyscraper opened and was taller,

    Five of today's ten tallest New York skyscrapers were between between 1930 and 1933. In 1933, New York enacted a 420 page code that regulated building limits that halted much construction. The code also removed New York's noted setbacks requirements and instead used a system of floor area areas. "Wedding cake" buildings ceased being built as glass and steel slabs were the new norm.

    Mumbai enacted a building height limit. This resulted in newcomers living in smaller units. It also created increased congestion.

    The author advises cities to replace the permit system with a fees system. Fees should be charged to pay for the social costs of buildings.

    Glaeser advises that preservation laws should designate a fixed number of buildings and that the list should be changed only slowly. He seeks to encourage building in areas that need not be preserved.

    The author encourages neighborhoods to have the authority to keep their unique characteristics. People should have more influence than should city planners on the directions of their community.

    An ironic consequence of efforts by Ian McHarg and others of building new suburban housing projects integrated with nature destroyed more nature from the resulting sprawl.

    Housing prices increase by 1.35% for a 1% increase in family income in that area. An area with January temperatures that are 5 degrees warmer than the national average have 3% higher housing prices.

    Houston has no zoning code. It provides more affordable housing than do most cities. Houston does have much sprawl and high energy costs.

    A gallon of gas, from refining to driving, uses 22 pounds of carbon dioxide. The average family is involved in emitting ten tons of carbon dioxide per year. Gas consumption, according to Glaeser and Matthew Kah, decreases by 106 gallons annually with a doubling of the number of residents per square mile.

    California has a good climate than doesn't require as much energy throughout the year as the rest of the nature.

    Centralized governments like Japan tend to have larger capital cities. People locate close to where political power exists. Many businesses want dealings with the government. Japan, even when economically poor during the 1960s, had a population better educated than in most other countries. Many young people started their careers in government employment. This educated workforce helped Japan achieve significant economic gains.

    Singapore grew by using both free markets and government directed industrialization.

    Cities with a highly skilled population are more apt to adjust over the loss of a major industry

    Cities drew from immigration that brings in new talent. A good education system helps city grow and innovate. Poverty programs should help people and not places.

    The U.S. population grew by 19.5% or more in every decade from 1790 through 1970 except once, the 1930s.

    As Glaeser put it, "The central theme of this book is that cities magnify humanity's strengths...Our culture, our prosperity, and our freedom are all ultimately gifts of people living, working, and thinking together...the ultimate triumph of the city."
    6 people found this helpful
    Report
  • Reviewed in the United States on October 28, 2014
    Cities succeed and fail based on numerous variables including population density, income, and overall growth. Edward Glaeser, an economist, takes his readers on a journey back through historical successful and not so successful metropolitan areas across the globe in his book, The Triumph of the City. He outlines his theses on different aspects of a city that often provide for a city to prevail through hardships; others are not so lucky. Glaeser’s main point of his book is that the paradox of cities revolves around a city’s ability to adapt to setbacks and thrive from prosperity. One of those setbacks Glaeser says deserves special attention is a city’s fast track to crime and how it can quickly deteriorate a great city. In fact, he claims that cities must manage things that threaten them in order to come out on top. His three most valuable points about crime revolve around poverty, social arenas, and Detroit’s decline.
    Glaeser’s hypothesis on crime revolves around the fact that it is inevitable; it is a result of less fortunate people taking refuge in the city for more opportunities. He asserts, “Cities are crime-prone mostly because the poor people who come to cities bring the social problems of poverty, like crime, with them” (Glaeser). In this sentence, Glaeser ties together poverty and crime and elaborates that crime is a by-product of the poverty that sets in. While this might seem like a shallow view of poverty on Glaeser’s behalf, he follows up by stating that this aspect of a city is rather inevitable. Poverty in a city is what helps make a city great because it provides opportunities for the poor that rural areas just cannot offer. So while they are a negative aspect of how a city operates, it is worth combatting the crime so the impoverished have a fair shot at succeeding. Glaeser’s take on poverty and crime here spins crime in more of a positive light as the aftermath of allowing the less fortunate the chance to succeed.
    On the other hand, Glaeser contradicts himself by commenting on the discrepancy in crime rates between the slums of Rio and Mumbai. He concludes that the differences in crime rates between Rio and Mumbai are attributed to the social community that is formed that either encourages or inhibits crime. For example, “Rio’s slums are famous for their trigger-happy gangs, but Mumbai’s slums are usually quite safe…Mumbai’s slums lack the dangerous feeling I have felt in Rio’s favelas or New York’s poorer areas in the 1970s” (Glaeser). Instead, he claims that the reason crime is not as prevalent in Mumbai as it is in Rio is because of the social space that it has to offer. Rio is crime-ridden because of the “trigger-happy” gangs that reside there. Mumbai, on the other hand, has a social space that provides a sense of community for the city and therefore is resistant to crime. I think this view on crime is a little shallow as well. I think there is a lot more than just the social aspect of crime in a city. I think he could have gone into more detail about how the social factors play into crime. For example, why Rio’s slums has relied on gangs for sustenance or how Mumbai’s community was developed to deter crime. In addition, I would have been interested in hearing how corruption plays a role in the policing aspect of cities which leads to a lack in the prevention of crime.
    Glaeser uses the example of Detroit to explore the city’s decline from start to finish, beginning with the demise of the auto industry which lead to excessive rioting. Detroit focused narrowly on the automobile industry in the time of Ford. They were so consumed with the production of the automobile that when the country’s industry was faced with foreign competition, riots broke out and tore through the city. The combination of the two forced the city into a downward spiral and led to many of Detroit’s inhabitants to move to the suburbs. This furthered the decline because it did not allow economic stimulation to help the city get back on its feet. While crime was not a direct cause of Detroit’s decline, it certainly played a role in its downward spiral. Glaeser’s argument here ties social and economic attributes together for an overall well-rounded conclusion. It is attributing Detroit’s decline to many variables that compounded and eventually destroyed one of the most historical U.S. cities.
    Edward Glaeser’s downplay of crime in a city does not diminish his overall goal of displaying the many different aspects of what makes a city triumph or fall. I think his economic background often takes away from the social aspects of how a city works which lead to his lack in social understanding of how crime develops in a city as well as the effects it has. While there are some shortcomings, his overall point is well thought out and researched. I would have been interested in learning about how metropolitan political corruption plays a role in crime. Also, not simply violent crime but also the many illegal activities of political figures and how corrupt leadership can negatively impact a city’s success.
    Cities succeed and fail based on numerous variables including population density, income, and overall growth. Edward Glaeser, an economist, takes his readers on a journey back through historical successful and not so successful metropolitan areas across the globe in his book, The Triumph of the City. He outlines his theses on different aspects of a city that often provide for a city to prevail through hardships; others are not so lucky. Glaeser’s main point of his book is that the paradox of cities revolves around a city’s ability to adapt to setbacks and thrive from prosperity. One of those setbacks Glaeser says deserves special attention is a city’s fast track to crime and how it can quickly deteriorate a great city. In fact, he claims that cities must manage things that threaten them in order to come out on top. His three most valuable points about crime revolve around poverty, social arenas, and Detroit’s decline.
    Glaeser’s hypothesis on crime revolves around the fact that it is inevitable; it is a result of less fortunate people taking refuge in the city for more opportunities. He asserts, “Cities are crime-prone mostly because the poor people who come to cities bring the social problems of poverty, like crime, with them” (Glaeser). In this sentence, Glaeser ties together poverty and crime and elaborates that crime is a by-product of the poverty that sets in. While this might seem like a shallow view of poverty on Glaeser’s behalf, he follows up by stating that this aspect of a city is rather inevitable. Poverty in a city is what helps make a city great because it provides opportunities for the poor that rural areas just cannot offer. So while they are a negative aspect of how a city operates, it is worth combatting the crime so the impoverished have a fair shot at succeeding. Glaeser’s take on poverty and crime here spins crime in more of a positive light as the aftermath of allowing the less fortunate the chance to succeed.
    On the other hand, Glaeser contradicts himself by commenting on the discrepancy in crime rates between the slums of Rio and Mumbai. He concludes that the differences in crime rates between Rio and Mumbai are attributed to the social community that is formed that either encourages or inhibits crime. For example, “Rio’s slums are famous for their trigger-happy gangs, but Mumbai’s slums are usually quite safe…Mumbai’s slums lack the dangerous feeling I have felt in Rio’s favelas or New York’s poorer areas in the 1970s” (Glaeser). Instead, he claims that the reason crime is not as prevalent in Mumbai as it is in Rio is because of the social space that it has to offer. Rio is crime-ridden because of the “trigger-happy” gangs that reside there. Mumbai, on the other hand, has a social space that provides a sense of community for the city and therefore is resistant to crime. I think this view on crime is a little shallow as well. I think there is a lot more than just the social aspect of crime in a city. I think he could have gone into more detail about how the social factors play into crime. For example, why Rio’s slums has relied on gangs for sustenance or how Mumbai’s community was developed to deter crime. In addition, I would have been interested in hearing how corruption plays a role in the policing aspect of cities which leads to a lack in the prevention of crime.
    Glaeser uses the example of Detroit to explore the city’s decline from start to finish, beginning with the demise of the auto industry which lead to excessive rioting. Detroit focused narrowly on the automobile industry in the time of Ford. They were so consumed with the production of the automobile that when the country’s industry was faced with foreign competition, riots broke out and tore through the city. The combination of the two forced the city into a downward spiral and led to many of Detroit’s inhabitants to move to the suburbs. This furthered the decline because it did not allow economic stimulation to help the city get back on its feet. While crime was not a direct cause of Detroit’s decline, it certainly played a role in its downward spiral. Glaeser’s argument here ties social and economic attributes together for an overall well-rounded conclusion. It is attributing Detroit’s decline to many variables that compounded and eventually destroyed one of the most historical U.S. cities.
    Edward Glaeser’s downplay of crime in a city does not diminish his overall goal of displaying the many different aspects of what makes a city triumph or fall. I think his economic background often takes away from the social aspects of how a city works which lead to his lack in social understanding of how crime develops in a city as well as the effects it has. While there are some shortcomings, his overall point is well thought out and researched. I would have been interested in learning about how metropolitan political corruption plays a role in crime. Also, not simply violent crime but also the many illegal activities of political figures and how corrupt leadership can negatively impact a city’s success.
    2 people found this helpful
    Report

Top reviews from other countries

Translate all reviews to English
  • Vir Bhasin
    5.0 out of 5 stars Must read for any economics buff
    Reviewed in India on December 3, 2017
    This book is the work of Mr Edward Glaeser's lifelong work on understanding the economics of the cities and their importance over anything else in the world.
  • paul88
    5.0 out of 5 stars Everything ok!
    Reviewed in Italy on August 13, 2019
    Everything ok
  • Amazon Customer
    5.0 out of 5 stars A load of info and historical perspectives to digest
    Reviewed in Canada on July 14, 2023
    Loved This book! Every chapter was loaded with interesting information and historical perspectives
    I highly recommend it
  • J_hill
    5.0 out of 5 stars Excelente livro
    Reviewed in Brazil on April 16, 2021
    Livro maravilhoso, mas as folhas são delicadas; é o tipo de livro para se priorizar a informação contida, sem levar muito em conta a estrutura física.
    Report
  • Benjamin
    5.0 out of 5 stars Urban planning
    Reviewed in Singapore on March 21, 2025
    Great book for urban enthusiasts